Monday, April 28, 2025
10:02 PM
Doha,Qatar
RELATED STORIES

Governments must cut their spending and spare the poor

Why do some governments spend more than others? The question is more complicated than it appears, especially in the case of European governments.

The answer may look obvious when comparing, say, Denmark (where public spending, excluding interest payments on debt, amounted to 58% of GDP in 2012) and the United States (where the same number was 35%). Extensive public services and a comprehensive welfare state appear to be the indisputable explanation.

The data seem to vindicate German Chancellor Angela Merkel’s famous statement that Europe’s problem is that it accounts for 7% of the world’s population, 25% of its GDP, and 50% of its social spending.

From this perspective, European governments face an uncomfortable choice. Most are seeking ways to contain public indebtedness, trim deficits and cut spending without making their poorer citizens worse off.

But, judging by the experience of the US and other non-European countries, they may have to choose between insolvency and inequality. Having reached the point at which taxes can scarcely be increased further, these governments cannot both repay their debts and keep welfare spending at current levels.

The answer, however, is less obvious when comparing European countries to one another. Most share a preference for socialising risk and an aversion to inequality – the pillars of the “European social model”. Yet their public-spending levels differ significantly.

The highest spender is Denmark, with its 58%-of-GDP mark, which is a whopping 13 percentage points higher than in Spain. Even more striking perhaps, French public bodies spend 12 percentage points of GDP more than those in Germany, with no significant difference in outcomes in terms of health, education, or poverty. This suggests that some countries are more efficient at social welfare than others.

Furthermore, some countries have succeeded in reducing their public spending significantly without changing their social model altogether. Swedish public spending is nine percentage points lower than it was in 1995.

There were welfare-spending cuts along the road, yet the country still ranks at or near the top of most development indicators and continues to be perceived as a social-democratic role model.

This is not to say that all European countries provide the same social safety net. Unemployment benefits or public pensions are not identical in, say, Ireland and Finland. But differences in public-spending levels are not matched one for one by differences in social outcomes.

There are several explanations for that. One is the sheer cost-effectiveness of public programmes. Some health-care systems are simply better managed than others, because expensive equipment is used more intensively, patients are provided with generics instead of premium drugs, and timely prevention helps contain treatment costs.

More efficient healthcare does not presuppose higher inequality; on the contrary, it may reduce inequality.

A second reason for the significant differences in European countries’ spending levels is that public and private expenditure can be highly substitutable. Contributions to a public pay-as-you-go pension system are very similar to those made to a mandatory private insurance system.

For example, one reason why France spends a lot on public pensions is that there are virtually no private pension schemes in the country.

If employees were mandated to subscribe to a company or industry fund, public spending would mechanically drop, but not much would change.

True, public pension schemes generally involve some degree of redistribution. But they mostly take money from employees when they are active to redistribute it to them when they retire.

The difficult question is whether employees in fact regard these contributions as their own savings or merely as taxes – in which case they may discourage labour or create incentives to work in the black economy.

In any case, if desired, substitution of private for public pension schemes may help reduce government spending without major distributive effects.

A third reason for the disparities in European public-spending levels is that governments often aim at alleviating the consequences of market inefficiencies – and miss the mark.

Consider housing. Public programmes are necessary to provide affordable housing to the poor and the young and to help foster energy saving.

But they often do much more: they provide unnecessary support to middle-class households – or, worse, subsidise landlords indirectly by helping tenants pay the rent. The same applies to labour-market or enterprise policies.

Public spending in these cases does not serve its stated aims; rather, it finances middle-class welfare or even capital owners’ welfare. Cutting such spending may be difficult in the short term, but it can be achieved without adverse social consequences in the medium term.

In the end, it is difficult to disentangle the various causes of higher public spending in some countries relative to others.

Clearly, some social models are more generous than others, and some are more efficient than others.

But, though some governments have no choice but to cut inequality-reducing programmes, and others may find it more politically expedient to change the distribution of income than to enforce efficiency, much can be done to improve the cost-effectiveness of public spending before reneging on a social contract. Europe’s governments can still trim public spending without undermining the European social model. - Project Syndicate

 

Jean Pisani-Ferry teaches at the Hertie School of Governance in Berlin and currently serves as commissioner-general for policy planning in Paris. He is a former director of Bruegel, the Brussels-based economic think tank.

 

 

Comments
  • There are no comments.

Add Comments

B1Details

Latest News

SPORT

Canada's youngsters set stage for new era

Saying goodbye is never easy, especially when you are saying farewell to those that have left a positive impression. That was the case earlier this month when Canada hosted Mexico in a friendly at BC Place stadium in Vancouver.

1:43 PM February 26 2017
TECHNOLOGY

A payment plan for universal education

Some 60mn primary-school-age children have no access to formal education

11:46 AM December 14 2016
CULTURE

10-man Lekhwiya leave it late to draw Rayyan 2-2

Lekhwiya’s El Arabi scores the equaliser after Tresor is sent off; Tabata, al-Harazi score for QSL champions

7:10 AM November 26 2016
ARABIA

Yemeni minister hopes 48-hour truce will be maintained

The Yemeni Minister of Tourism, Dr Mohamed Abdul Majid Qubati, yesterday expressed hope that the 48-hour ceasefire in Yemen declared by the Command of Coalition Forces on Saturday will be maintained in order to lift the siege imposed on Taz City and ease the entry of humanitarian aid to the besieged

10:30 AM November 27 2016
ARABIA

QM initiative aims to educate society on arts and heritage

Some 200 teachers from schools across the country attended Qatar Museum’s (QM) first ever Teachers Council at the Museum of Islamic Art (MIA) yesterday.

10:55 PM November 27 2016
ARABIA

Qatar, Indonesia to boost judicial ties

The Supreme Judiciary Council (SJC) of Qatar and the Indonesian Supreme Court (SCI) have signed a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) on judicial co-operation, it was announced yesterday.

10:30 AM November 28 2016
ECONOMY

Sri Lanka eyes Qatar LNG to fuel power plants in ‘clean energy shift’

Sri Lanka is keen on importing liquefied natural gas (LNG) from Qatar as part of government policy to shift to clean energy, Minister of City Planning and Water Supply Rauff Hakeem has said.

10:25 AM November 12 2016
B2Details
C7Details